Categories
Blockchain Financial talks at dinner table

All About Cryptography

The Kingstons agreed to dig into more details of cryptocurrency mining asked by Emily. Although the issues are more technical than all the previous conversations the family has had, the conversation style keeps the text short and pointed because anyone can ask any questions along the way. At the end of day, however, they did not go any further than talking about hash, hash function and cryptography.

Greg: Let’s consider the mining question Emily raised at the very beginning. Remember we were talking about a decreasing reward for miners? Turns out that the Bitcoin algorithm also has a changing level of difficulty for mining, which can either go up or down, depending on the number of miners in the game and how active they are mining.

Joy: That’s right. Please don’t feel overwhelmed Emily because this issue is directly related to what mining is. We’ll get there to answer your questions.

Emily: Thank you for telling me that. Meanwhile, I’ll keep asking questions along the way if you don’t mind.

Greg: Of course not! Let me begin from one concept called “difficulty epoch” as discussed by a CoinDesk article. Each epoch corresponds to 2,016 blocks of transactions, which in turn correspond to roughly two weeks. After the current difficulty epoch is reached, the difficulty level will be updated either up or down, based on the number of miners and their activities in the last two weeks.

Joy: Yeah, the goal in the algorithm is to finish verifying a block in ten minutes. If last two weeks have seen less than ten minutes the difficulty level will be up, otherwise down.

Lily: So it looks like not only the entire supply of Bitcoin will reach 21 million coins in 2140 but the pace of releasing new bitcoins is also determined by the algorithms at 10 minutes per block.

Joy: Yeah, the whole process is transparent. You can prove it with the numbers. 10 minutes per block means 6 blocks in one hour, 144 blocks in one day of 24 hours, and 2,016 blocks in two weeks or 14 days because 2,016=144 x 14.

Greg: Not meant to confuse you, but there is another milestone related to the decreasing coin reward to miners. Remember we learned yesterday that four every four years the reward will decrease by half. That four years correspond to 210,000 blocks created or confirmed.

Emily: How do the algorithms control levels of difficulty?

Greg: The key is to change the number of leading zeros in the target hash function.

Emily: Wow, what’s a hash function?

Joy: We talked about hash function before when we were discussing NFTs. A hash function is best to be called a “fingerprint machine.” In math terms, hash function is nothing but algorithm that accepts different inputs or data or messages and then produces uniform sized “fingerprints” that can be called “hashes,” “hash values,” “hash sums” or “message digests.” I can show you a static picture here, but the guy named Haseeb Qureshi does a better job in a blog showing a really neat dynamic cartoon picture.

Hash input, hash function and hash digest

Greg: Haseeb Qureshi did a good job but this video is by far the best I’ve ever seen after reading, searching and watching many other pieces and sources. It explains a whole bunch of concepts like block, blockchain, hash, hash function, nonce, distributed network, tokens and Coinbase and nicely put them together with a little demonstration that clearly and visually get the ideas crossed. It’s so intuitive that people as young as Jason can understand because everything is right there in front of your eyes. It’s about 18 minutes long but I guarantee that it won’t waste a single minute of your time.

Emily: Wow! I’ve never seen you so excited before. We sure will watch it later.

Greg: Just a bit background information for the video. At the beginning of the video you will see the term “SHA-256,” that means “Secure Hash Algorithm” that produce hashes that are 256 bits long. Bear in mind that when it comes to computer terminologies, we don’t count “words” but only “bits” and “bytes.” One byte is 8 bits. So 256 bits is just 32 bytes.

Emily: Why should we care about these details?

Greg: You don’t have to. We could sit here talking about bits, bytes and hexadecimal numbers all day. But the important thing to keep in mind is that the SHA-256 is a hash function, or more accurately a cryptographic hash function — the machine that makes hashes or “fingerprints.” There are other hash functions but SHA-256 is the most popular one. If you must know one hash function, SHA-256 would be it. Bitcoin uses SHA-256, for example. I learned from this article by n-able.com that “The US government requires its agencies to protect certain sensitive information using SHA-256.”

Kimberly: What make SHA-256 so much liked?

Greg: That article by n-able.com again offers a good summary: (1) one way function from input data to hash and almost impossible to figure out what the input data is even if you know its hash because “A brute-force attack would need to make 2256 attempts to generate the initial data.” (2) Uniqueness of hash, once again because the “2256 possible hash values (more than the number of atoms in the known universe), the likelihood of two being the same is infinitesimally, unimaginably small.” (3) the avalanche effect that “a minor change to the original data alters the hash value so much that it’s not apparent the new hash value is derived from similar data; this is known as the avalanche effect.” These are the major ones; I will add more later when we compare hash function with encryption.

Joy: Now that you mention encryption, I remember reading somewhere that cryptocurrency needs both hashing and encryption.

Greg: That’s true. The nice thing though is that encryption and decryption, hash functions, and digital signature algorithms are all parts of cryptography. This is why Bitcoin and others are all called “cryptocurrencies” because they all use the same foundational technologies of cryptography.

Emily: What does the word “cryptography” mean?

Greg: Good question. This article from Investopedia offers a good explanation. I have it downloaded to my phone. Here it is: “The word ‘crypto’ literally means concealed or secret. ‘Cryptography’ means ‘secret writing’ — the ability to exchange messages that can only be read by the intended recipient.”

Emily: Sounds like cryptography is all about security and confidentiality of information or data.

Greg: More accurately it’s a decentralized way of keeping information, data and transactions secure, a way that does not require a third party or a central authority. Furthermore, the technologies not only provide security but also efficiency. If you watch the video I recommended, you will see that we can put in all the stuff from the Library of Congress and the hash function still produce one hash digest that is only 256 bit long!

Lily: What about encryption and decryption? What are they and why we need them?

Greg: They serve different functions for cryptocurrency. So far we have been talking about cryptocurrency mining, which relies on the hash functions. But when we get to the transactions between digital wallets, encryption and decryption become the key tool.

Kimberly: How do hash function and encryption differ?

Greg: That’s a hot topic and much discussion surrounding it. The first key difference is that encryption is a two way process, meaning you first encrypt the plaintext data to make it secret or unreadable, which is called “ciphertext”, and then you need to decrypt to make it readable.

Joy: This is like sending and receiving a telegraph in the old days.

Greg: Exactly. Say someone’s grandma is seriously sick, she’d rush to the post office and writes down the words “Grandma sick, come home!” to be sent to her brother. The post office worker would first translate, encrypt that is, the words into a bunch of codes, and then send to her brother. Once the telegraph arrives at the receiving post office near where her brother lives, someone else in that post office will translate, decrypt this time, the codes into plain English.

Kimberly: How is the hash function different?

Greg: Hash function always works one way, meaning there is no decryption. Once the input data, messages or transactions were hashed, we don’t want them to be decrypted or to make the hash readable by a human. For a hashing function, such a reverse process — if succeeded — would be a disaster because it means the hash function failed to do its job.

Kimberly: But why is that a good thing? It’s like sending a telegraph out that no one can read and understand, right?

Greg: I thought about that for several days by asking myself the same question as you just did: What if someone needs to read and understand the original input, not just the hash? I searched online using that question and could not find any answer.

Kimberly: So do you have an answer now?

Greg: Suddenly it came to me yesterday that it’s not the right question to ask, because it failed to take the purpose of blockchain data into consideration. When people put transaction records in a blockchain, they want two things: One, keeping those records in the chain permanently and remain unchanged forever. Two, making the authenticity of all the records in each block easily and quickly proven. For those purposes a one way hash function works out perfectly.  

Kimberly: Could you elaborate on that?

Greg: It is directly related to a very nice property of the hash function. Not only is it a fingerprints machine, but the machine is extremely efficient. Remember I talked about earlier that even if we put all the books and journals from the Library of Congress into one block — I know that’s impossible given the 1 MB per block data limit set by Satoshi — the SHA-256 hash function would still produce just one hash that is 256 bit long?

Kimberly: Yeah, why is that relevant here?

Greg: Well, keep using the Library of Congress example, and still assume the entire collections were fit into one block, with the hash function working properly, even if I changed one comma in one book — and there are 167 million items when I checked it last night — to a period, the hash will be completely different.

Joy: Yeah, even a tiny change in the input will certainly lead to a completely different hash. This is called “Avalanche Effect.”

Kimberly: Those are impressive, but I still don’t see their relevance with our discussion here.

Greg: Think of it: How would you make sure that none of the records in a block has been tempted? Checking all the records one by one, or just look at the hash function to see if it has been different?

Kimberly: Oh, I see! A hash function makes it very easy to find out any changes made to any record in a block. I can buy that, but what about encryption? Does it do the same thing as a hash function?

Greg: Smart question! If I say “yes,” then we can use encryption to still get what we want. Unfortunately, the answer is “no.” You see, the output from encryption varies, depending on the size of the input. That means longer inputs or “plaintexts” will have longer outputs or “ciphertexts.” This is just like telegraph, the more words you send, the longer the telegraph and more money it costs you.

Joy: Very interesting. The other reason we can use hash function for blockchain is that all hash functions are deterministic, meaning that given the same input, only one hash digest will be produced. Therefore, while it is virtually impossible for anyone else to reproduce the input from hash, whoever owns the input record knows perfectly well what the input is. She does not have to do the “reverse engineering” like a hacker would have to.

Emily: You say, “virtually impossible,” is it still possible to find the input once you have the hash?

Joy: It is possible but highly unlikely. The way to do it is through the so called “brute force attack,” meaning to run through all the possible combinations until hitting the target. This requires great resource with very low chance of success. Remember the reason we were told earlier: A hackers would have to make 2256 attempts to generate the initial data.

Lily: I am thinking of passwords that we use every day. They are usually not very long, so which function is best for protecting passwords, hash function or encryption?

Greg: Good question. The answer is still hash function but for a different reason. Can you guess what it is? It’s because decryption — the process that makes an unreadable text readable — is a bad idea that is asking for trouble. This article correctly points out that “it’s more secure to store the hash values of passwords instead. When a user enters a password, the hash value is calculated and then compared with the table. If it matches one of the saved hashes, it’s a valid password and the user can be permitted access.”

Joy: Speaking of passwords, I’ve read an interesting story that is almost funny: Turns out if you limit the passwords to a four-digit number, the choices made by many people are highly predictable. I still remember that the top choice is “1234,” followed by “1111” and “0000.” Those made the “top three” list.

Lily: So is encryption any good at all for cryptocurrency? It sounds like hash function is all we talk about.

Greg: That’s a question for another day.

Categories
Blockchain Cryptocurrencies & NFTs Financial talks at dinner table

Blockchain & Cryptocurrency

After yesterday’s talk on editable blockchains, the family comes back today to continue their conversation on blockchain and cryptocurrency mining. The conversation is mostly between Emily, who believes she is not good at technical details, and her parents.  

Greg: I hope you all had the time to find something related to blockchain. Yesterday we talked about philosophical issues of absolute or relative immutabilities, today I think the issues may be more detailed and more technical.

Emily: I guess I’m not good at technical stuff. Can you help me with “Proof of Work?” versus “Proof of Stake?” I know one of the top cryptocurrencies, Ethereum I think its name is, is moving toward “Proof of Stake” while Bitcoin stays with “Proof of Work.”

Kimberly: That’s right. I read a report from the Fortune magazine that Ethereum is currently running both “Proof-of-Work” and “Proof-of-Stake.” But when they finish the highly expected upgrade, which we don’t have a set date yet, it will be “Proof of Stake” only.

Lily: And I read an article published by Bitcoin magazine that says Bitcoin will not, and could not, switch to “Proof of Stake” because Bitcoin code is immutable.

Joy: It’s important to remember that first of all, “Proof of Work” and “Proof of Stake” are different ways of doing cryptocurrency mining. Perhaps even more importantly they are both “Proofs of Resources” in the sense anyone possessing more resources has a better chance to become a winner in crypto mining.

Emily: You said “a winner” so there is just one winner? Also what is cryptocurrency mining? Why are so many people interested in mining?

Joy: Let’s begin from the last question, which is the easiest: People want to mine crypto for the same reason today as people came to California during the “gold rush” in the 19th century. They want to win something big.

Emily: How big is “big?” I mean the size of miner reward.

Joy: Let’s find out. Jason, could you Google today’s Bitcoin price for us please?

Jason: Sure. “Hey Google, what’s the price for Bitcoin today?” Here it is: $31,119.80 for one bitcoin on May 15, 2022.

Joy: Thank you! Just to be clear, a winning miner will get far more than $31,000 because she receives more than one bitcoin, 6.25 coins to be accurate for now, every time she successfully mined one block of crypto transactions. We multiply the unit Bitcoin price of $31,119.8 Jason just found for us by the number 6.25, which is $194,498.75.

Emily: You said, “for now.” So 6.25 coins are not constant all the time?

Joy: No, how many coins the winner gets are not constant but keep decreasing by half roughly every four years, until it goes to zero in 2140 when there will be 21 million Bitcoin in total.

Emily: How does the decreasing reward work?

Joy: It’s called “block halving event” and let’s show it with numbers. I will quote this website called bitcoinblockhalf.com that does a good teaching job. I have it downloaded to my phone. Here it is: “When Bitcoin first started, 50 Bitcoins per block were given as a reward to miners. After every 210,000 blocks are mined (approximately every 4 years), the block reward halves and will keep on halving until the block reward per block becomes 0 (approximately by year 2140). As of now, the block reward is 6.25 coins per block and will decrease to 3.125 coins per block post halving.”

Emily: I understand these numbers but why the decreasing rewards. That’s not fair to later miners don’t you think?

Joy: This is a good time to tell the entire crypto rewarding story, or why miners get rewarded in the first place. Let me ask a question first: Who do you think is authorized to issue the paper money?

Lily: The central banks. In the US that’s the Federal Reserve.

Joy: That’s right. Now, who has the authority to issue Bitcoin, Ethereum and other cryptocurrencies?

Lily: No one. They are decentralized currencies I believe.

Emily: Wait, what are “decentralized currencies” versus “centralized currencies?”

Lily: The dollar bills we use every day are centralized money because every dollar bill is issued and controlled by the Federal Reserve, nobody else can do that. That monopolistic and central control makes the dollar centralized currency.

Greg: Now that we are on the topic, centralized versus decentralized is not the same as distributed. I read an article talking about how the three systems differ. Briefly, centralization or decentralization refers to mode of control, while distribution is about location.

Joy: Yeah I heard about that, too. Bitcoin, or more accurately its blockchain, is decentralized but also distributed: “Decentralized” because decisions are made not by a central authority but by consensus; “distributed” because the nodes in a peer-to-peer computer network are all over the world.

Nodes in a peer-to-peer network

Greg: Here is a picture of the three systems I found online. Centralized has all links pointing to a single center, kind of like the Chinese political system where everything is eventually determined by Beijing. Decentralized does not do that, although it may contain hubs of links, kind of like the federation system this country has, where hubs are different states. Distributed has neither a center nor hubs. It is like “direct” or “pure” democracy if you will, getting rid of the representatives altogether.

Lily: I don’t know you guys but if we were treating all three systems as modes of control for decision making, I will pick the one in the middle, the decentralized mode, although I understand the “distributed” system is for locations, not exactly for controlling.

Kimberly: I feel the same! Decentralized has advantages from both sides, just like “representative democracy” is better than centralized dictatorship and distributed “direct democracy.”

Three Systems of Decision Making & Location

Greg: Going back to cryptocurrencies, they are all issued and controlled by algorithms, not by government agencies.

Emily: What are algorithms?

Greg: An algorithm is a predetermined set of rules for computing. In this country we have rule of law for governing human behaviors. Algorithms are the rule of law for governing computer behaviors.

Emily: Interesting. I did not realize how important algorithms are in our lives.

Greg: Bear in mind though algorithms are initially designed by humans. Once started, an algorithm can obtain its own life, or works by the designed logic until we decide to change the rules later.

Joy: I really want to comment on the algorithms in cryptocurrency, more specifically Bitcoin, has been well thought of. Let’s ask ourselves this question: Why was the algorithm designed to reward miners? This is highly relevant to Emily’s question of why the miner rewards are reduced by half every four years.

Lily: From what I have read, it’s all economics. When Bitcoin first started, it must compete with the monopoly power of central banks. The way it competes is through mobilizing as many people as possible, to get them involved in creating and owning cryptocurrencies. Offering reward in Bitcoin — not in dollars — is the best way to go, because miners would have their personal interests lined up with increased value of Bitcoin, or all cryptocurrencies for that matter.

Joy: That’s right! Decentralized power comes from having a large number of people all working for the same goal with shared interest. The economic reasoning behind cryptocurrency rewarding is to give higher reward at the beginning, when Bitcoin was a brand new “startup money” and not many people knew about it.

Lily: It also reflected the lower value of Bitcoin in terms of dollars back when it started in 2009.

Joy: Exactly! The priority back then was to attract more miners to join the digital “gold rush,” to make some “cryptocurrency noise,” to increase decentralized power, which all add up to benefit the value of Bitcoin or other cryptocurrencies.

Kimberly: I see the logic now: The algorithm assumes the value of Bitcoin will get higher and higher as time goes on, so there is no point in keeping the same number of rewarding Bitcoin for the winners.

Emily: I see it, too. Even though the number of Bitcoin rewarded goes down from 50 in 2009 to 6.25 today, the dollar value is perhaps higher than 2009 given the current Bitcoin price. The miners today can take home much more than earlier miners.

Greg: That’s exactly what happened. One thing I love about this country is that you can always find the information you want. I was searching for the price history of Bitcoin and came across this article from Investopedia called Bitcoin’s Price History. We can see Bitcoin had a price of zero when it was introduced in 2009. That changed on July 17, 2010, when its price jumped to $0.09. So indeed the 50 bitcoins received by the first miner meant nothing in 2009, while 6.25 bitcoins are enough to bring six digit income now, even with the recent cryptocurrency price crash.

Joy: This is why I had a hard time believing Warren Buffett actually said that he would not buy all the Bitcoin in the world for even $25, because he said he could not find any use of Bitcoin. He seems to have forgotten what he has been doing for all his life: investing in something for better returns. That’s exactly what one can do with Bitcoin. Let’s say someone sold Buffett 50 bitcoins back in 2010 at the historical price of $0.09 per coin, and he kept those until today, he would have gained how much? Jason, could you do the calculation for me?

Jason: No problem. 50 bitcoins times the unit price of bitcoin today at $31,119.8, that’s $1,555,990, more than $1.5 million! Let’s take out his historical cost of $4.5 in 2010, his net profit would still be $1,555,985.5!

Greg: Let’s calculate his rate of returns. Divide his gain of $1,555.985.5 by his cost of $4.5 and then multiply 100 to make it a percentage figure. What do we have, Jason?

Jason: Wow! That comes out to be 34,577,456%!

Greg: That was phenomenal, and I doubt if Buffett’s other investment records can beat that.

Emily: I still have a concern for miners after 2140, when the algorithms will stop paying reward as there won’t be new Bitcoin released once the algorithm reaches its goal of 21 million Bitcoins.

Joy: I won’t worry too much about that. Miners are still capable of charging fees against Bitcoin users because transactions will still need to be audited by miners. Miners have other privileges like voting for Bitcoin rule changes as well.

Greg: I think we’ve had an interesting discussion on things like decreasing mining reward, centralized versus decentralized currencies, distributed nodes and the value of cryptocurrencies as “investible assets.” But we have yet to answer Emily’s questions about what mining is in any details, about “Proof of Work” versus “Proof of Stake.” We’ll have to stop here as it gets late. Do I have everyone’s consensus to continue the talk tomorrow?

The answer is “yes” and that marks the end of conversation for today.

Categories
Blockchain Financial talks at dinner table

Blockchain & Relative Immutability

It has been weeks since the Kingstons had a conversation on NFTs, Bitcoin and Blockchain based on the blog post written by Devin Finzer, co-founder of OpenSea the largest NFT marketplace in the world. Greg has been busy writing a research paper, and the rest of family had to mind their own business. But today is a good day as everyone feels the need to catch up where they left off last time.

Kimberly: I feel like we should talk more about blockchain. Last time we briefly touched on it, like how a blockchain keeps ownership of NFTs or transactions unique or “non-fungible.” But there must be more to blockchain, right?

Jason: Wait, what is a transaction that you guys keep talking about? Is it buying or selling something, like I paid my friend Lee $1 yesterday to buy two sweetest apples from his family trees?

Joy: Yeah, business transactions are the most obvious that involve at least two people and usually money changing hands. But not all transactions involve two people nor money. If your friend simply gave you an apple for free, that could still be called a transaction.

Emily: Some transactions do not involve different people, either. If I change my weekly budget to cut down food spending and increase book spending, those changes are recorded as transactions, too.   

Greg: To answer Kimberly’s question, of course there are more, much more to blockchain. Last time we were mostly talking about NFTs, the stuff that Devin Finzer and OpenSea focus on. We can go deeper into blockchain today if you guys want.

Joy: Let’s do that. To start, I remember reading this interesting article from Investopedia with a flashy title of “Forget about Bitcoin: Blockchain is the future.” It basically calls Bitcoin a small side show and the blockchain the big drama.  

Lily: I’ve seen that, too. Somehow I feel the article is exaggerating the case. Some people are only interested in Bitcoin and know little about blockchain, while others believe blockchain represents the future technology, or the greatest invention since the Internet.

Joy: I agree. we don’t have to forget about Bitcoin in order to remember blockchain. Historically, blockchain came to us much earlier than Bitcoin did, so in that sense blockchain is the “chicken” and Bitcoin the “egg.”

Kimberly: It is also true though that many people discovered or became aware of blockchain only because of Bitcoin. It’s almost like they ate the “egg” first to then realize the value of the “chicken.”

Emily: Yeah, like I did not know much about the Titanic ship tragedy until the other day when I watched the movie Titanic with Kate Winslet and Leonardo DiCaprio in it.

Jason: So you are saying the Titanic movie is your “chicken,” the real Titanic ship is your “egg?”

Emily: I’m saying it can go both ways. A “chicken” for someone can be the “egg” for someone else. We don’t have to settle down on one order and put that in stone.

Joy: You have a good point. If I were to write that Investopedia article, I would use a title like “Appreciate Bitcoin but Understand Blockchain.” People use flashy titles all the time to catch more eyes and ears, and I get that. But everything has a limit, we should not go too far on that.

Greg: I like the way Emily said it: putting something in stone. That old expression now may have a new way of saying it. Some people may stop saying “set in stone.” They’ll probably say, “set in blockchain!”

Kimberly: Interesting. I assume it is because blockchain makes everything in it immutable or, to put it in plain English, permanently unchangeable. But how exactly does blockchain do that?

Greg: First thing first, I don’t want you guys to think blockchains are absolutely immutable. Everything is immutable with the right amount of resources, like money and time.

Lily: Are you saying the stuff inside a blockchain is changeable? I have never heard anyone saying that before, everyone seems to be saying a blockchain is immutable database.

Greg: There are two kinds of thinkers in the world. Some just see further than the rest of us, not necessarily because they are smarter — they usually are — but more because they ask the right questions, assign themselves more challenging jobs and do not blindly follow others’ thinking trail just because it’s popular.

Joy: You are talking abstract. Any example please?

Greg: I’ll cite this article by Dr. Gideon Greenspan who works on private blockchains, and I believe it raises some excellent points. I’ve downloaded it to my phone.

Emily: Wait! What is a “private blockchain?” Are you talking about different ownerships of blockchain? So a private blockchain is privately owned by someone?

Joy: Public or private blockchains are not exactly about ownership. A private blockchain for example can be owned by governments just as likely as by private firms. I think it is better to call them “permissioned” or “membership” blockchains, meaning you need permission or membership to get into them, much like you need a valid username and password to enter your email accounts.

Greg: That’s right. Since Bitcoin started on a “permissionless” blockchain, most blockchains are in that category, meaning they are open for any strangers to see all the transactions inside. They are “open to public” but not necessarily owned by public.

Jason: Unlike the public library we visited last weekend that is open to public and is owned by the city government.

Joy: Correct. Speaking of “permissioned” blockchain, I’ve read something from Investopedia that says some banks claim they build blockchain but they’re not, because their blockchain is private or requires permission, which according to the author, has little to do with the innovation behind Bitcoin.

Greg: The voices against private blockchain are louder than that because, like Greenspan puts it: “immutability has become a quasi-religious doctrine – a core belief that must not be shaken or questioned.” Imagine the response when someone’s religious belief was challenged.  

Lily: Interesting. I did not see immutability as a religious doctrine for blockchain but did take it for granted. So what does Greenspan say about blockchain immutability?

Greg: He challenges the common wisdom and calls the blockchain immutability a “myth.”

Joy: Is he trying to use a flashy title to make news?

Greg: I can’t read what’s on his mind, but he does make several convincing points. First and foremost, he answers the fundamental question by critics of private blockchain: What is the point of developing a blockchain if its contents can be changed or edited? Would anyone guess what his answer is?

Joy: I don’t know what he would say but I would argue that we humans want different things. Sometimes information security or immutability is the top priority, for that blockchain immutability serves us the best; but other times controllability is the king, meaning we want to keep the capability to change things as we see fit. At the end of day, no matter how powerful our computers are, we still want control them, not they control us.

Kimberly: I agree. For financial transactions it makes perfect sense to keep all the records straight and not to be modified or edited once they enter a blockchain. We also don’t want our passports, our driver’s licenses or our tax returns to be changed, especially not by anyone else.

Emily: I see what you mean. But mom is right, some records or transactions we do want to make changes from time to time to fix human errors, frauds. The law changes, too, which means legal contracts sometimes need to be updated.

Joy: That’s right, even smart contracts may need updates.

Lily: I think part of the problem is that blockchain was made popular by Bitcoin. Some people only see the Bitcoin side of the blockchain story. I don’t know if this is a good analogy but to me blockchain is like the gunpowder: We can use it to make fireworks for the Fourth of July, but the same gunpowder can be used to make weapons. A kid only knows the former, but a terrorist is only interested in the latter.

Emily: So to ask why anybody wants an “editable blockchain” is like a kid asking why anybody wants to use gunpowder for anything other than fireworks.

Lily: Something like that. But dad, you haven’t told us what the answer from Greenspan is.

Greg: Well, his answer is long and although I like the points he makes, he does sidetrack himself a bit and spends much time telling us why no immutability is perfect even with “permissionless” blockchain. His point is well taken there because it is true immutability depends on the tradeoff between what we want and what resource we have. So immutability is a relative thing, not an absolute one.

Lily: So he did not tell us why an “editable blockchain” is needed.

Greg: Not really. Your mom actually does a better job in answering that “why” question. There is also this webpage by Accenture called “Editing the Uneditable: Blockchain Needs to Adapt to an Imperfect World,” which essentially says the same thing as your mom did. Let me see if I can find the page.

Kimberly: The title seems to offer a clue to the answer: We need editable blockchain because the world is not perfect and static.

Greg: Yeah. I’ve found the page and here it says: “In most instances, immutability is an obvious benefit. But it’s also increasingly apparent that instances will arise where absolute immutability is a hurdle standing in the way of blockchain’s adoption.” Then it goes on to list areas where editability or mutability is good and needed, like in data storage, illegal actions, operational errors, permanent mischief and regulatory concerns.

Kimberly: I can understand why relative immutability is good and necessary, but I have a more basic question: Relative or absolute, how does blockchain ensure immutability?

Emily: I want to ask that question, too. How about you, Lily?

Lily: Same here.

Greg: I think this is a good place to stop for today. Why don’t we all do some homework on that and come back tomorrow to share our findings?

Everyone agrees and the talk comes to an end.

Categories
Cryptocurrencies & NFTs Financial talks at dinner table

A Deep Conversation on Fungibility

After the second family conversation yesterday, the Kingstons are anxious to talk more about NFT after doing their homework reading of the “NFT Bible” by the co-founder of OpenSea (the largest NFT marketplace in the world), Devin Finzer.

Emily: I’m glad dad recommended this reading; I feel I know so much more now about NFTs than before.

Greg: So what is the number one thing that impressed you guys the most?

Kimberly: I would have to say it is the point of “non-fungible assets are the norm; fungible assets are the exceptions.” The more I think of it the more I agree. We have seen far more unique things in the world than identical things.

Greg: I would be careful about calling fungible things “identical.” In the business world “fungible” essentially means “interchangeable” or “tradable” — even though two things may not be identical in every possible way. To borrow Lily’s term, things are “commonsense fungible” enough to be interchangeable or tradable.

Joy: I wonder if we should put “interchangeable” and “tradable” together, even though they sound similar. It seems to me that being identical is the least forgiven and most strict. Even identical twins are not exactly identical to the extent they expose to different environments. Being interchangeable is more forgiven because similar things are interchangeable even though they may or may not be identical, like two apples from the same tree in the same season. Tradable is most forgiven because we can arrange to trade so many different things, some of them not deemed interchangeable at all, like Russia exports oil and natural gas and imports iPhones and iPads.

International trade talked by Joy

Greg: Anexcellent point! Yes, many fungible things are interchangeable, but both fungible and non-fungible things are tradable. Perhaps international trading involves more non-fungible stuff given the different levels of development.

Lily: One advantage of focusing on “tradeable” things is that trading always involves negotiation. I think many things have fungibility that is also subject to negotiation.

Kimberly: An interesting thought that’s in line with Devin Finzer, who also emphasizes the relative and subjective nature of non-fungibility. Here it says “fungibility is relative; it really only applies when comparing multiple things.” And he goes on by saying two business class sets on an airplane is more fungible than a “first class” and an “economy class” tickets.

Fungible is exception; Non-fungible is the norm

Greg: I agree fungibility is relative but disagree that it is only useful for comparing multiple things. You can compare two things meaningfully for fungibility, just remember their fungibility is not fixed or absolute but changeable or conditional, depending on scenarios, contexts, time, people and history.

Emily: In theexample used by Devin Finzer you can see he is thinking of the same way. He talks about someone preferring a window seat would not trade his window seat with an aisle seat. But for someone else who does not care as much, the two seats are more fungible.

Window or aisle seat?

Lily: Yeah, the same goes to the idea of “semi-fungible”: Items within the same class are more fungible than items between classes, like two box seats in a football stadium are more fungible than one ordinary and one box seat, just like two Teslas are more tradable than one Tesla and one Ford.

Emily: Oh, that’s what “semi-fungible” means? I was wondering about that. What about the name of non-fungible tokens? I was thinking that if non-fungible was the norm, then non-fungible tokens literally mean “normal tokens,” not really an exciting name.

Lily: “Normal tokens” are not exciting I agree, but if we switch to the other side of the same coin and just call tokens “unique” that should be more appealing, as we all like things that are unique.

Emily: That’s true and in that sense, the name “non-fungible tokens” defines the nature of things pretty well because all tokens are unique in the NFT world, and each is different from others.

Greg: Yes, you may even say being unique is the only common feature shared by all NFT items on a blockchain.

Joy: Speaking of uniqueness, it just hits me that the whole idea for companies to develop brands is to make their products or services unique, not interchangeable with non-brands or other brands, even from the same category of goods or services.

Kimberly: Good point. And companies are not the only ones doing that, buyers do, too. I have a Chinese friend who once told me that the Chinese prefer the number “8” because it sounds similar to “Fortune” in Chinese. If that’s true, a Chinese customer may think a gold bar with the ending serial number of “8” is more valuable than an otherwise identical gold bar with a different ending number. I bet she would refuse to trade her “8” numbered gold bar with another.

Identical or unique gold bars?

Greg: Interesting points you’ve all brought up. We have been told in schools that commodities, money and gold are textbook examples of fungible or interchangeable things. Now we know even textbook examples do not always hold and are subject to negotiation. Both sellers and buyers have the power to turn interchangeable things into non-interchangeable.

Emily: What about the opposite direction? Like can we turn non-interchangeable into interchangeable?

Joy: Your question sends us back to the “tradable things” I said earlier. T-Shirts and airplanes are normally not interchangeable, right? But international trade did just that: Developing countries export T-shirts, tea, coffee, banana, raw materials so they afford to import airplanes from developed countries.

Kimberly: That happens every day. The fungible money plays a crucial role here: Anything can be tradable as long as they all have values measurable by money.  

Lily: I’m thinking that the reason non-fungible becomes the norm is because we all want to be unique, like I won’t trade my pants, jackets, skirts and shoes with Emily or Kimberly, even if they were the same brand, size or color. All my stuff has my name on it, and I don’t want to trade them with others.

Kimberly: I think it also depends on level of economic development. My Chinese friend told me that in the days before China opened its door to the world, some families in the rural area of China were so poor that the entire family had only one pant or one jacket. Whoever needed to get out of the bed got to wear that pant, others all hided under a family comforter. These people had no choice but to share the same “family pant.” Non-fungibility was not even on the agenda.

Emily: Shocking and sad story but good for China to put those days behind! I was wondering if and how the blockchain has changed things around.

Lily: Yeah, I was wondering about that, too. We should expect at least some changes, right?

Joy: We do, one big change has been pointed out by Devin Finzer that although we’ve had digital assets since the internet age, we’ve never really owned them like in the sense of physical world. That digital ownership story is changed by the blockchain technology.

Kimberly: That’s right. Devin talked about how blockchain makes it possible not only to prove who owns what in the digital world, but also for owners to move their digital assets around, like we do in the physical world.

Emily: Iwish there were more details, like how does blockchain make things different in the digital world?

Greg: There are many discussions on advantages and usages of blockchain, like Bitcoin, digital ownership, immutability or unchangeable, enhanced security, distributed ledgers. But all these I believe are based on non-fungibility of things. Digital ownership, digital credential, immutability, security, these things are baseless without digital assets being unique.

Emily: How does blockchain ensure non-fungibility then?

Greg: We can look at it at two levels. The first is at the block level. We all know blockchain is a chain of blocks. Each block of information has a unique timestamp and more importantly a unique “hash function,” which according to this Wikipedia page, is “any function that can be used to map data of arbitrary size to fixed-size values.” This guy named Haseeb Qureshi has a better way to put it: The hash function is a “fingerprint machine.”

Digital fingerprint

Joy: Yeah, I remember reading that piece. He has a neat cartoon picture to show how different inputs to the hash function come out as a fixed sized “fingerprints.” So if the input is “Hello!” the output will be some combination of letters and numbers. But if the input is “I love dogs!” then the output will be something different. They all will have the same size, like 256 bits. If the NFT is your passport, it will come out uniquely, never the same as someone else’s passport.

The “magic” hash function

Lily: So a hash function is as unique as a fingerprint.

Greg: More accurately a hash function produces unique fingerprints, depending on unique input data. This is how each block in a blockchain will be earmarked by its own unique fingerprint.

Joy: The article compares “normal” hash functions with “cryptographic” hash functions. The latter come with more security features and more robust than the former. It adds three more features like one-way function, avalanche effect and collision resistant.  

Greg: That’s right. But even a normal hash function is nice and powerful. One of its features is deterministic, which ensures that if you give the same input, the hash function will always produce the same output. Fungibility in the physical world is retained in the digital world.

Kimberly: But there are numerous records, transactions or NFT pieces within each block. How do they remain unique?

Greg: Let’s get the name straight first. In the physical world things are three dimensional existences, but in the digital world I believe everything becomes a token, whether you have Bitcoin, transaction records, personal credentials, driver’s licenses or passports, deeds, contracts, NFT artworks, games or cartoons.

Kimberly: Okey, so how do we keep tokens unique?

Greg: Simple, they all belong to different owners, creators or developers, and they have public and private keys in digital wallets. You can check out more information for the keypairs and how they work online. Essentially you can send transactions to public key, but you need private key to unlock them and prove you are the owner.

Joy: This validation process using private keys is why Devin Finzer says the blockchain finally solved the ownership problem.

Greg: Plus moving tokens around anywhere and anyway owners want. Once we have non-fungibility established, things become more fungible — no pun intended.

Joy: Maybe we should stop here and save more topics for another day.

All: Good idea!

Categories
Cryptocurrencies & NFTs Financial talks at dinner table

Why Some NFTs Have Shocking Prices

After the first family conversation on NFT ended with an open question, today everyone is anxious to get back together at the dinner table because they have something other than foods in mind.

Greg: So did anyone want to share the thoughts on Lily’s question of why some NFT products having a shocking price tag?

Kimberly: Well, I think the key is to remember the NFT market is not just a buyers’ market, but also a new market. We have never seen such a market before because the whole blockchain technology was simply not there.

Joy: Excellent point! That definitely has something to do with the skyrocketing prices that Lily was talking about. What people do in a brand new market? They speculate because nobody knows exactly where the market is heading even in the short future.

Greg: I agree. This always happens: When we do not have solid facts to back up our thinking one way or the other, we use our imaginations to fill out the gap left by weak or scanty evidence.

Lily: But I still don’t understand how speculation pushes up the price of some but not all NFTs.

Kimberly: Well, in a buyer’s market only buyers have power, the sellers are left to suffer from low price. But in a new market both sellers and buyers are allowed to speculate, and both can shape the market through speculations, making the game fair and more interesting.

Greg: What Kimberly is saying is that although the NFT sellers lost the traditional monopoly power of scarcity like Picasso had, they gain the power of speculation in a time of high uncertainty.  

Lily: I understand that part. But why only some but not all NFTs receive astonishing price?

Emily: I think I have an answer. In a way the NFT market is like the California Gold Rush that we learned in history class. Everyone had high hopes, and everyone was trying to get rich quickly.

Greg: Interesting comparison. The Gold Rush showed us how powerful speculations was. Let’s be honest, without the Gold Rush there won’t be 300,000 people moved from all over the world to California; without the Gold Rush the city of San Francisco and the state of California would not have been born so early.

Joy: That’s true. Never overlook the power of speculations because changes made by speculations are just as real as those driven by full facts.

Kimberly: One important lesson from the Gold Rush — the one that helps answer Lily’s question: Only a few people ended up getting rich from the Gold Rush, most earned little more than they had started with. Remember the Charlie Chaplin movie “The Gold Rush?”

Lily: Oh yeah, a great movie! So this NFT market is like the Gold Rush Déjà vu all over again.

Greg: Well, yes and no. NFTs are way more sophisticated than digging gold in the old days. For example, all gold miners were competing with each other to find gold, not to create anything that nature did not directly provide. NFT market is full of creators and creativities.

Joy: The gold miners also only needed to find gold and never worried about finding buyers, because everyone wanted to buy gold once the miners found it.

Kimberly: We also did not hear stories like how the miners coordinated to form any brand. Basically zero branding power from miners.

Emily: Yeah, the gold buyers were not much better. They just sit there waiting for the miners to come to them. Today the NFT buyers are highly developed but also highly divided. Some are willing to pay big ticket price for items that others couldn’t care less.

Lily: So you are saying it is the divided buyers who pushed up the price of some but not all NFT items.

Emily: I think so. The article from the Washington Post I was talking about yesterday described how a few NFT marketers like “Bored Apes” and “CryptoPunks” managed to win big from selling NFT collectables.

Kimberly: I have a feeling that the current NFT market emerges more by design than by random events.

Emily: You are right on that. According to the article, the cryptocurrency and blockchain community wanted to use NFTs to help them gain market traction and acceptance. “They want to create a sensation, to whip up publicity for NFTs in particular and cryptocurrencies in general.”

Lily: No kidding. Nothing else is more powerful than the headline news that some people became overnight rich from NFTs.

Emily: A good example is this NFT artist named Mike Winkelmann, who called himself Beeple, flew to the art fair in Miami in private jet — this is the same guy whose entire wardrobe used to be worth about $600, and by the time he landed in the airport, his bank account received $56 million from the record sale at Christie’s. It’s like a jackpot.

Lily: Cases like that add fuel to more speculation.

Emily: It sure did. Let me quote the Washington Post article again: After the “Beeple sale” on March 11, 2021, the total NFT sales reached $12 billion by early December last year, up from $546 million in the first half of 2021.

Joy: In the worst case scenario we may even see “winner takes all,” when a few winners can charge any high prices they want while the rest receive almost nothing.

Greg: We have had a wonderful conversation so far, but we may want to go deeper than talking about a newspaper article. I believe we can learn a lot from the industrial insiders. I came upon this wonderful blog last night that I have not finished reading yet. It had an interesting title of “The Non-Fungible Token Bible: Everything you need to know about NFT,” published in January 2020 by this guy named Devin Finzer, the co-founder of OpenSea, the largest NFT marketplace in the world. How about we all read that blog and come back to talk more tomorrow? I can send the link of that blog to your phone if you are interested.

Everyone except Jason and Cleo agrees to read the blog and that is the end of the second family conversation on NFT.

Categories
Cryptocurrencies & NFTs Financial talks at dinner table

First Family Conversation on Non-Fungible Tokens

Three days had passed since the Kingston family last had a long chat at the dinner time. Today Emily raised a question that interested everyone.

Emily: So has anybody heard about the thing called NFT?

(All except Cleo raised hands)

Emily: Jason, you heard about NFT, too?

Jason: Yeah, why, you found it hard to believe? A friend of mine was a big fan and he kept telling me all the stories about NFT, like some kid in Asia sold his selfies for more than a million dollars.

Kimberly: Oh I heard crazier stories than that: This Seattle based teenager artist built a collection of NFTs valued at more than $26 million.

Emily: Yeah, I heard that one, too. The funny thing is that the kid was selling stickers and prints for $5 a piece online just one year ago.

Kimberly: So who can tell us what NFT stands for?

Lily: I know the first letter “N” means “Non” and “T” for “Token” or Tokens. Someone once told me the meaning of “F” but I forgot it now.

Emily: “F” means “Fungible,” which means “replaceable” or interchangeable with something identical. So “Non-fungible” basically means not replaceable or not identical to something else. But if something is non replaceable, it must be unique. That’s what it says.

NFTs that Emily asked about

Lily: How do you know so much about NFT? Are you gonna create your NFT and sell it?

Emily: Not really. Our arts teacher asked us to write an essay on NFT.

(Turning to Greg), speaking of the essay, dad, what do you think of NFT? Do you see much value in it?

I look at some NFTs and I don’t understand why someone’s selfie deserves more than a million dollars.

Greg: It’s natural to feel that way, and I am sure you are not the only one with questions. I myself have been thinking of it a lot lately.

Kimberly: Do you look at it more from a financial perspective or a commonsense perspective?

Greg: It’s interesting you put that way, but I believe both ways are needed to fully understand NFTs. In fact, not only financial and commonsense but we may even need an artistic perspective. After all, those non-fungible tokens are mostly seen as arts.

Joy: Wow. This conversation is getting more interesting! I have a nonprofit client who is familiar with arts and museums. We were chatting the other day about NFT, and I asked her opinion. She said the same thing you just said that it is easier to understand NFTs if you know arts.

Emily: Oh good! I’m glad you guys mentioned that. I came across this interesting and fairly recent article on Washington Post published last December that talked about just that. It’s pretty long but let me pull it out on my phone to give you a few highlights.

Greg: Is the one written by a journalist who went to Miami, Florida to cover American’s most prestigious art fair, I forgot what is called.

Emily: Yeah. It is Art Basel Miami Beach, which attracts the world’s art collectors.

Greg: That’s a good piece and I liked it. It has lots of information in it and brought us the latest stories in NFTs, crypto, blockchain and the art world.

Emily: I think so, too. Anyway, the first section of the article has a definition that says an NFT “is a unique digital representation of a good — for our purposes, a work of art. It’s akin to a certificate of authenticity or a deed and it’s recorded on a blockchain.”

Jason: I have heard the name before but what exactly is a “blockchain?”

Emily: I’ve learned a lot this time from writing my essay. The best way to define a blockchain conceptually is a “distributed and decentralized database.” In case you did not know, a database is just a bunch of data stored in a computer that allow people to access for information.

Blockchains asked by Jason

Jason: Well, how do they make database “distributed and decentralized?”

Emily: The key is to create “information redundancy.” Before blockchain, databases are separated and isolated from each other, each owned by a different organization.

Jason: What’s wrong with that?

Emily: Well, to see what’s wrong, the first thing is to recognize that those databases are centralized because no matter how big a company or a government agency is, it only has one database.

Kimberly: Yeah, now that you mentioned it, a good example is IRS, the government agency that collects citizens’ taxes. Pretty much everyone pays taxes, right? And the IRS has a huge database for all taxpayers’ transactions, not just this year but way back. Think of how many records there must be in the IRS database.

Emily: Exactly. The danger with centralized databases is that they attract hackers. But even without hackers there are natural disasters like fires, earthquakes, floods, power outages and lightening hits. It is called “a single point of failure” for all centralized databases.

Jason: So blockchain stores the same database with multiple copies in multiple places.

Emily: Exactly. Multiple databases are decentralized because there is not a single database that controls all others. All duplicated databases are equal and if one database is hacked or corrupted, others won’t, and we can quickly find out the bad copy and kick it out of the system.

Greg: What you said is a nice conceptual definition of blockchain, I want to add a technical note to it: Anything registered in a blockchain is truly non-fungible, meaning unique or unreplaceable because it is designed to be that way. A blockchain is a bunch of blocks each with a unique time stamps with information in it and these blocks are connected to form a chain.

Kimberly: So let’s see, that means no two Bitcoins are identical because they each will have a unique trace on the blockchain, right?

Greg: That’s exactly right and that’s the beauty of digital currency, unlike fiat currency, where one dollar is just one dollar, the one dollar bill on my left hand is fungible or identical with the one dollar bill on my right hand.

Jason: What is fiat currency?

Greg: Oh, it’s just a fancy way to call the traditional money issued by government, like the American dollars we use every day, or Japanese Yen, or the Euros.

Joy: Speaking of fiat money, I’m thinking that no two dollars are identical, either. I bet the one dollar on your left hand will have a different serial number than the one on your right hand. However, the two dollars do have identical value, just like two Bitcoins.

Greg: That’s right, I forgot about the serial numbers. Good point!

Jason: I have a few dollar bills left from my lunch money. Let’s see: Yeah, this bill has a serial number F30022163M, the other one says K61556364C. They are different.

Kimberly: If blockchain can make two units of the same digital currency, like Bitcoin or Ethereum, non-fungible or unique, it certainly will make all NFTs unique, right?

Lily: I think we should separate two kinds of uniqueness. Yes you are right to say that on a blockchain everything is unique, and nothing is identical with anything else, even between two bitcoins or two dollar bills. But do we really care about that kind of technical or trivial uniqueness? I doubt it.

Emily: That’s an excellent point. I was thinking along the same line but with NFTs. One big problem with NFTs is that people can always make copies of the same popular NFTs for themselves. If they all registered their individual copies on a blockchain, they will be unique in some ways, like when they were entered, and who the owners are. But from commonsense perspective, that kind of uniqueness is really no big deal, as these copies are all identical except for the blockchain generated uniqueness.

Kimberly: I like the term “blockchain generated uniqueness.”

Joy: So the issue is how we maintain “commonsense uniqueness” above and beyond the “blockchain uniqueness.”

Jason: But why does commonsense uniqueness matter?

Kimberly: Because we human beings all want to be unique; you don’t want to be just a carbon copy of someone else, even with someone you love or admire, right?

Greg: Going back to what Emily said, the problem we face today is not scarcity but the opposite of it: abundance. We can easily copy and paste anything digital that in a commonsense view are identical to each other. This is very different from the old days when making an identical copy of the masterpiece was impossible. The best one could do was to have a fake one that looks like the original, never identical.

Lily: Like back in the days for Picasso, Davinci or Monet, right?

Greg: Yeah. Today’s technologies allow us to produce identical copies so easily and in so large quantity that the “art hackers” in the old days could not even dream about.

Joy: So you are saying the big question today is how to restore or save scarcity in the age of abundance?

Greg: Exactly.  

Joy: Well, one way to do that is through algorithms. Like the number of Bitcoin was programmed to be no more than 21 million ever. There, not only do we have scarcity but know exactly the size of supply.

Emily: The same logic works in NFTs. It turns out owning a free and identical copy is not enough for some people, they want to possess the one that is original and are willing to pay a big price for that.

Greg: So Bitcoin scarcity is created by the creator of the digital currency, but for NFTs scarcity is saved by some buyers on the demand side.

Kimberly: That makes sense, because there is always only one original NFT, regardless of how many free copies out there.

Lily: Not only that, but the more copies out there, the more valuable the original becomes. Whoever bought the original can always brag that she or he bought the one out of a million, which sounds much better than one out of 10.

Greg: This gets me to think that the basis of value today is different from Picasso’s time. In the old days, the value of artworks was attached to the artists, who were “the one and the only” to produce masterpieces that nobody else could match.

Joy: So only masters could produce masterpieces. Using the chicken-egg metaphor, the masters were “chickens,” masterpieces were “eggs,” and the chickens always came first. As long as there is only one Picasso in the world, the value of his artworks would be fixed, regardless of how many imitations there are.

Kimberly: But isn’t that always the case that a particular artist produces a particular piece of artwork, so the “chickens” always come first?

Greg: Well, yes and no. Different NFTs will be produced by different artists just like before but today’s artists do not have the same “monopoly power” as Picasso had. Think of what has changed?

Kimberly: Well, like you said earlier, there is an abundance of virtually identical copies today.

Greg: Yes. In the old days there was just one copy for each masterpiece of Picasso for the entire world. It’s a natural monopoly. If you wanted to see the masterpiece, you visited a museum. But nowadays everyone can have a personal copy of a NFT if she wants.  

Kimberly: But that’s just easy accessibility, which does not kill monopoly power. There is still only one Picasso in the world.

Greg: There is only one Kimberly Kingston in the world, does that give you the same monopoly power as Picasso? Monopoly power is not about being the only one, but about your capability of changing or influencing the behaviors of others.

Kimberly: I see. Sounds like the abundance of identical copies shifts the power from NFT artists and sellers to buyers and we have a “buyers’ market” for NFTs.  

Lily: But wait, in a buyers’ market the price goes down, why do we still see some skyrocketing prices in the NFT market?

Greg: Interesting question. But it’s getting late and let’s continue the conversation tomorrow.

Video highlight of what the family has learned on NFTs
Categories
Financial talks at dinner table Securities Investment

The Howey Test & Investment Contract

After their conversation yesterday on securities, Greg asked everyone, except Cleo, to do a bit of research on their own about the “Howey test” that the US Supreme Court used to define an investment contract, which in return will define securities. Today they come together at the dinner table again to present and trade their findings besides eating.

Security law & regulations this post focuses on

Greg: So, what did you guys find on the Howey Test? Who wants to tell us the background story behind the Howey Test?

Lily: Let me try it. According to the piece I’ve read, a Florida-based Howey Company sold land with citrus groves to buyers. They then asked the buyers to lease their land back to them, so they could grow and sell the citrus and split the money with the landowners.

Kimberly: I smell something strange. Why can’t Howey just use the land they own to grow and sell citrus? What’s the point of selling the land and then leasing back?

Lily: I wondered about the same. There must be something beneficial from doing the leaseback deal, most likely the company thought they did not have to register the transaction with SEC, and that was where their legal troubles started.

Jason: Wait! What is SEC?

Lily: Its full name spelt out is U.S. Securities and Exchange Commission. It’s a government agency in charge of regulating the securities markets and protecting investors. Right, dad?

The SEC Seal

Greg: You got it. It’s created 1934 by the Securities Act of 1933 and Securities Exchange Act of 1934, the two milestone laws in securities. Just remember this: Much of the securities rules and regulations didn’t exist until after the Great Depression in 1920s and early 1930s. They are the lessons learned by this country from the crisis.

Lily: Yeah, so in 1946, the SEC sued Howey because it believed the citrus deal qualified as an investment contract and therefore, Howey should have registered with SEC. The case went all the way to the U.S. Supreme Court.  

Emily: I’m surprised that the Supreme Court agreed to hear it. To me it’s a small case.

Greg: Well, the Supreme Court in 1946 was not the Supreme Court today. What is important then is different from what is important now. It all changes by time.

Lily: After the court hearing it was decided that Howey should register with the SEC because the citrus business was an investment contract. The four conditions listed by the Supreme Court ruling then became one of the most famous case laws of this country.

The U.S. Supreme Court

Kimberly: I find it interesting that the whole definition of securities hinges on this single test. Mom was right when she called this Howey test “Almighty” yesterday.

Emily: That’s because the ruling of the Supreme Court was rich, containing four elements if I remember correctly.

Kimberly: You are right, I have written these elements down: The first is investment of money; the next is into a common enterprise; then investors must have expected profits and finally the profit is solely generated by efforts of others, not by the investors.

Greg: Since you’ve written it down, could you try to summarize the Howey Test for us?

Kimberly: It’s easy given the order I put the four elements down: Howey test says someone must invests money to a common enterprise or a company for the purpose of receiving profits that are solely generated from others’ efforts and time. If all four conditions are met, you have an investment contract and that defines a security.

Greg: Sounds good to me! Did anyone have questions?

Emily: I do! I have a friend whose dad invested in a farm — not with money but with a tractor he inherited from his father. Would that count as investment?

Greg: It would. “Invest money” has been later expanded to “invest asset” or valued resources. There is a catch, though, and not every book or article mentions it: Everyone will accept money, but not everyone will accept a tractor, depending on what the common enterprise needs. The investor would have to find out before investing.

Kimberly: What exactly is a “common enterprise?” We don’t hear that term often.

Common Enterprise that Kimberly asked about

Lily: From what I searched, that term has never been precisely defined. Most federal courts defined it as “horizontal,” meaning several investors pooling their money or assets together to invest in a project. A common enterprise is similar to a “shared project” in that sense. But other courts have different definitions.

Greg: I think it is important to keep in mind that the SEC was created to tighten the control and regulations of securities, cleaning up the mess left by the Great Depression. With that in mind, the Supreme Court cared more about substance than form in its ruling.

Emily: What do you mean “substance over form?”

Greg: Let’s use the Howey example, the leaseback deal that the Howey Company did with the landowners in Florida. There was never a stock or bond issued by the company. Would that count as investment contract? We all know now that the Supreme Court said “Yes.” The landowners were investing their assets in the Howey Company, and therefore must register with the SEC.

Joy: Yeah, speaking of substance over form, I found this other legal test called the “Forman test.” It’s quite interesting because it tells us what a security is not, even though the transactions involved names like “stocks” or “shares.”

Emily: Really, that’s interesting. Tell us more about it please!

Joy: You guys can Google it yourself by using “the Forman Test of securities.” But the basic story was that this nonprofit organization called United Housing Foundation developed some low-cost, government subsidized housing units and asked that anybody wanted to rent an apartment must buy eighteen shares of stock first. The shares were not transferrable — remember dad said ownership liquidity for securities, that anyone can buy or sell any number of shares at any time? Well, this one did not have any liquidity, and shareholders had no voting rights, either. When they leave the housing unit they must sell the shares back to the nonprofit organization at the original price they bought.

Low income housing units in the Forman Test of securities

Emily: How did the Supreme Court hear the case? I mean what happened that triggered Supreme Court hearing?

Joy: Like most legal battles, this one started when private interests were threatened. The nonprofits decided to raise the price for the units and 57 residents decided to file a lawsuit against the nonprofit. Interestingly, instead of accusing the nonprofit for simply raising price, these residents argued that the nonprofit violated the securities laws by issuing unregistered stock. The nonprofit argued back that the stocks it issued were not securities. That’s what the Supreme Court had to decide.

Kimberly: What’s the verdict of the Court?

Joy: Well, like dad was saying, substance over form. The Court basically agreed with the nonprofit and declared that just because it called its shares “stock” did not automatically make it an investment contract. The Court said something like when the transaction was motivated by consumption rather than investment for profit, the securities laws do not apply.

Lily: In other words, it is not how people call it, but what is really going on between investors and companies that matters.

Greg: Yeah. Some people get really creative with playing the names game just so they don’t have to register with SEC. It’s understandable because, let’s face it, it’s no fun to do the paperwork with government. Not just the paperwork but they must disclose all the crucial financial information to the public, like quarterly financial reports.

Joy: The Forman test was a big deal because it says you must separate consumption from investment.

Greg: Not all states agreed with the Forman test, though, despite the Supreme Court ruling.

Emily: Oh, really? Can states disagree with the Supreme Court?

Greg: Sure, there are federal laws and state laws, and if they disagree, your case will depend on which state you live or do business with.

Emily: Could you give us an example?

Greg: Yeah, I did my homework last night and found that there was one historical case right here in the Bay Area, in Marin County to be accurate. In 1959, let me quote this website, “some enterprising developers bought land in Marin County to develop a country club. To pay for some of the costs of building the club, they sold charter memberships in the club. The members would not share in the profits or ownership of the club but would have the right to use club facilities.”

Golf /Country Club in the Risky capital test of California

Kimberly: Let me see if I could put it in plain English: Some Marin County real estate developers needed money to build a country club. So they announced that anyone investing in money would receive a membership to use the club, not an ownership of the club.

Greg: That’s it, you did a good job in translation!

Kimberly: That to me is another “consumption but not investment” case like the Forman test says.

Greg: Exactly. By federal definition the membership would not count as securities because investors only get the right to use, not the right to own the club. But the California Supreme Court disagreed and came up with a new test called “Risk capital test.” It said even if investors only got the right to use, they invested money in a risky business that could not guarantee the consumption right in the future.

Emily: Very interesting! So cases like that will be counted as securities and must register with the state of California.

Greg: Yup.

Kimberly: That says a lot because almost all investment of money involves risks, and few if any enterprise would guarantee the return of profit.

Greg: It did say a lot. Instead of profits in the future, it looked backward to risk involved when investors wrote checks to business. The California Supreme Court apparently wanted to protect the public from risky investment schemes with uncertain or risky results.

Emily: Dad, I would like to return to Howey test. Why did the Supreme Court asked for having someone else’s time and efforts to qualify for a security? Why can’t it allow investors to take control of the company and be the managers?

Joy: I have been thinking of the same question myself, and I think I have an answer: Separating investors from company managers helps the company grow and reach a scale.

Emily: Are you saying a security is not like a family business? You know, like mom and dad do everything themselves: investing their own money, working together to control everything in business.

Family Business Emily talked about

Joy: That’s a good way of saying it.

Kimberly: I have a simpler explanation: Just think about borrowing money from a friend. If you own a business and wanted to borrow money from your friend, would you like to have that friend manipulate or manage your business, just because s/he lends you money? Of course not.

Joy: An excellent point. It reminds us that all laws are based on common sense.

Lily: I think the other reason is efficiency: Many investors know nothing about a particular business, and they may not be interested in it, but they are the ones with the money. Why not invest the capital and let someone else run the business. Everyone is happy and gets to do what they do best.

Joy: Another good point! I want to clarify one point about family business: At first they do everything by themselves but later when they grow bigger, they will hire someone else for managing the business. Some family businesses may also need more capital to grow. If they decide to go to public for funds, they turn themselves into the securities market.

Emily: If a family business stays private and never issues stocks and never lists itself on the stock market, would it qualify as a security?

Joy: It’s funny you asked. I came across this notion of “private securities” earlier. Apparently securities include both public and private types. It’s just that most securities we know are public.

Emily: So how the private securities differ from public?

Joy: A privately owned security does not issue any stock to the public. It is also not required to register with the SEC and do all the disclosures like public securities must. Of course, its downside is not to be able to sell stocks to the general public, only to accredited investors.

Emily: Who are the accredited investors?

Accredited Investors Emily asked about

Joy: I did some follow-up research and found that an accredited investor may be an individual or an entity like an organization, a firm, a bank, an insurance firm. Basically they are financially sophisticated, like a stockbroker or a licensed financial advisor, or with so much money that they do not need the protection by SEC.

Kimberly: I heard about accredited investors before. My school once invited a startup founder to speak to us and he mentioned that they prefer to get private funds from accredited investors, not through IPO …

Jason: What’s IPO?

Kimberly: It stands for Initial Public Offering, to raise capital from the public for new companies. The startup will sell shares of their stock to everyone who wants to buy. Of course, it’s public, so SEC will be involved. The speaker said they didn’t want to go through all the regulations and paperwork, so they chose to go private.

Joy: Speaking of startups, did you hear the term “Unicorn?” That’s a term used in the venture capital industry to describe a privately held startup company with a value of at least $1 billion.

Jason: Could you give me some examples of Unicorn?

Unicorn Startup Joy asked

Joy: This one I am sure you have heard: ByteDance, who owns TikTok, and SpaceX by Elon Musk.

Jason: Oh yeah! Let me check their valuation. Oh, ByteDance is valued at $140 billion, and SpaceX is at $100+ billion. By the way, how do they know the value of a startup?

Greg: The key is to separate two values: Intrinsic versus market. A startup is about to enter the market but not yet, so we don’t know its market value. But experts can come up with an estimated intrinsic value based on future earnings or some other company attribute unrelated to the market price of a security.

(At this point the dinner table conversation ends.)

Categories
Financial talks at dinner table Securities Investment

The Opening Conversation on Securities

A quick reminder of the family members participating in the conversation:

Joy, managerial consultant
Kimberly, 12th grader
Jason & Cleo, 5th & 1st Graders
Emily, 8th grader
Greg, finance professor
Lily, college student

It is a sunny day in the San Francisco Bay Area where the Kingstons live. Joy the mom usually has a busy schedule but today she came home early and prepared the meal for the big family. When she saw her husband, Greg, before the meal, she could not wait to ask him a question:

Joy: Honey I am glad you are home! Guess what, I was at a client meeting early afternoon and one of my clients asked me a question that was totally out of blue. She wants to know how to define securities, you know, stocks and bonds. I told her I’d have to ask my husband for more details. What would say to her if she asked you in person?

Greg: Interesting question! (Turning to Cleo and Jason, the youngest daughter and son both in primary school): Did you learn from the school about what securities are?

Jason: Not that I can remember. But I can Google it. (Jason pulls out his Pixel 5: “Hey Google, define securities.” Google returned entries from Oxford languages in four categories: “All,” “Politics,” “Finance” and “Police.”) Dad, you want the financial definitions, right?

Greg: Yes that’s right.

Jason: Here you go. It has two entries. The first one says: “A thing deposited or pledged as a guarantee of the fulfillment of an undertaking or the repayment of a loan, to be forfeited in case of default.” The second says: “A certificate attesting credit, the ownership of stocks or bonds, or the right to ownership connected with tradable derivatives.” Wow, a lot of strange words for me!

Greg: Well the first is basically saying the same thing as collaterals. Please check on the definition of collateral, C-O-L-L-A-T-E-R-A-L.

Jason: Hey Google, define “collateral.” Here it is: “Something pledged as security for repayment of a loan, to be forfeited in the event of a default.” It sounds similar to the definition of securities but what do all these mean?

Greg: Let me ask you a question. I remember last time your buddy, Michael I believe his name is, wanted to borrow your bike for one day. Why did you ask to keep his iPhone before lending your bike to him?

Jason’s favorable bike

Jason: Because I was concerned that he may damage my bike, and I almost said no to him. Keeping his iPhone made me feel a little bit better or safer.

Greg: That’s it. You had something similar to a collateral from Michael.

Jason: Oh, really! That’s it?

Greg: Yeah — in spirit, not exactly in monetary term because you guys never agreed that if Michael broke your bike, you’ll keep his iPhone, am I right?

Jason: No, of course not! I did that just to make me feel better and safer.

Greg: So strictly speaking the iPhone is not a collateral but the basic idea is this: Someone wants something valuable from you, and you ask something valuable in return as a kind of guarantee, or a token that make you feel better and safer. Just remember the key difference is whether you can permanently keep the iPhone — that’s what the word “forfeit” means — in case Michael smashed your bike. If you could then it is a collateral or a security, otherwise it is not. 

(Turning to Joy): Sorry we haven’t got to address your question. Your client was clearly asking about the second definition that Jason was reading out. Jason, could you read that second entry again?

Jason: Sure: “A certificate attesting credit, the ownership of stocks or bonds, or the right to ownership connected with tradable derivatives.”

Greg: That basically says securities are ownerships, either currently or in the future, either complete or fractional/partial.

Stock certificate for ownership that Greg talks about

Jason: I didn’t see anything that says future or partial ownership.

Greg: This is the tricky part of formal definitions. They tell you something you must know, but oftentimes you must possess additional knowledge to be able to completely understand the words. The more you know, the better you understand. In this case, I know securities involve future and partial ownership because that is what financial derivatives do.

Kimberly: So dad, do you think the definition is a good one?

Greg: It’s as good as can be stated in a few words. Securities are a full pack of knowledge points, impossible to be covered in one or two sentences. You really need a Wikipedia entry to cover them all.

Joy: Would you offer a more complete view to us, like what is the major parts that are missing? I want to impress my client, you know.

Greg: In that case, the definition Jason just read is not even remotely complete. It says nothing about risk, nothing about ownership liquidity, nothing about investment contract, nothing about common enterprises, nothing about profit expectation and passive income. It misses completely the legal test of Howey defined by the Supreme Court.

Investment Agreement in the Howey Test

Joy: Wow, a lot of misses. let’s slow down a bit and say one thing at a time, shall we?

Greg: Sorry about that. Let’s begin with risk. Like many things in the world, securities contain value but also risk. In fact, we can say that the minute you take risk out of securities, they are no longer securities. I always like to add two letters “I-n” to the front, so that we say all securities are “insecurities.”

Emily: Interesting and I have never heard that one before. Could you give us an example of something that has little or no risk and not a security?

Greg: Sure. All standard insurance products carry no risk because as long as you pay your premium, you are guaranteed for the death benefits and cash value. We don’t call insurance products securities. For people who are retired, their annuities are also risk free. Not surprisingly, they are not securities. Finally, your savings and checking accounts in the bank are protected by FDIC, they are not securities.

Cleo: What is FDIC?

FDIC seal Cleo asked

Joy: It is Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation, an insurance company that protects depositors. Say someone saves $2,000 in his Bank of the West account and one day the bank declares bankruptcy, the person will get his $2,000 back from the insurance firm even though his bank is closed for good.

Emily: Oh that’s good. I was watching the movie Something the Lord Made the other day on Netflix, it shows this great guy Vivien Thomas saved his tuition money for college in a bank and lost it all because the bank was closed for bankruptcy.

Greg: Yeah, they created FDIC in 1933 exactly because the Congress saw thousands of bank failures in the 1920s and early 1930s. Did you guys know that the money for FDIC is from the premiums paid by the banks? They are not paid by our taxes. It’s really one of the greatest programs in the world! If you look at the FDIC website, you will see that ever since the birth of FDIC “on January 1, 1934, no depositor has lost a penny of insured funds as a result of a failure.” That’s how safe your money is with the bank.

Jason: How about something that is risky but not a security?

Lily: Gambling is risky, but it is not security.

Kimberly: but I heard people saying investing in stock market is just like gambling at a casino.

Joy: I’ve heard that, too. Sometimes people just want to dramatically simplify things to make them easier to understand or to remember. But how long do you stay in a casino to gamble? One hour? Two hours? Whole day? An entire long weekend? For most people, it is less than three days. But investing stock market is typically much longer than three days, sometimes one’s lifetime.

Lily: Also most people know they will end up losing money in a casino but expect making money from a stock market.

Joy: Yeah, especially when you go long term in the stock market.

Cleo: But daddy took me to a horse racing the other day and told me horse racing was gambling.

Joy: That may not be completely true. Horse racing is a legitimate sport but can be a way of gambling. Not all racetracks allow betting on horses, though.

Horse racing first time for Cleo

Greg: You are right. Note the gamblers on a racetrack are just like gamblers in a casino, they play the game quick and short.

Joy: So what’s the next thing that the definition missed?

Greg: It’s called “ownership liquidity,” basically a fancy way to say that one can buy and sell his or her securities to anyone else in the market upon a short notice.

Kimberly: And why is that important?

Greg: It makes securities more attractive than your savings and checking accounts in the bank. Here is why: You can cash your securities out almost as quickly and conveniently as you can from your bank accounts, but you expect much higher returns than what you earn in interests from a bank.

Lily: But money in the bank is safer with FDIC, right? You don’t worry about losing it like sometimes you do with securities in the stock market.

No risk, no gain. Some are willing to take more risks than others

Greg: True, and that’s the whole point of “no risk, no gain.” Securities have risk and bank accounts don’t, so securities bring higher gains than a bank account.

Joy: Okay, what’s next on your list of misses?

Greg:  Let me see, I think it’s investment contract. This is fundamental and covers all the other issues like Howey test, expected profit, common enterprises and passive income.

Joy: Sounds like we are switching from business to law.

Greg: That’s because the US Supreme Court was involved and came out with a legal definition of securities that all come down to this thing called “Howey test.”

Joy: But when I invest our money into Google and Apple, I do not remember signing contracts with anyone.

Greg: The regulation is tight for security firms and also brokers and advisors but light for individual investors. You do not have to sign a formal contract, although the brokerage company may ask you to sign the paper to open your account. That has nothing to do with the Howey test. 

Joy: So what is this almighty Howey test?

Greg: Instead of me talking all the time, how about we end here now, and everybody does his or her research online for the Howey test and we reconvene tomorrow to see what we get?

(Turning to Joy): Did you tell your client you will get back to her tomorrow?

Joy: No, I don’t get to see her tomorrow, we meet once a week.

Everyone agrees with the research idea and the conversation stops.

Categories
Cryptocurrencies & NFTs

CBDC By All Means

For those paying even limited attention to the news, it is almost impossible to finish a day without hearing words like “Cryptocurrencies,” “NFTs (Non-Fungible Tokens)” and “CBDC (Central Bank Digital Currency),” especially after the Super Bowl 2022. The best question to ask at this point is not whether crypto will stay and grow, but how to deal with changes in currency — something that has not happened for decades or a century — to make the transition more smoothly, costing less and gaining more.

CBDC = Authoritarianism?

Some commentators, like this opinion piece by Aubrey Strobel, went out of their ways to argue that we should avoid CBDC by all means because it symbolizes authoritarianism. If the US adopts CBDC, it “will be the end of American freedom” according to Strobel, and “the American government will be on a surefire path to authoritarianism.” “CBDCs would create an authoritarian surveillance state and constitute a severe overreach of power.”

Strobel is not alone, and she has companies in the US Congress. For convenience I will only cite the words from Congressman Tom Emmer (R-MN), which were cited in this Harvard Business Review article, “Central banks increase control over money issuance and gain insight into how people spend their money but deprive users of their privacy.” Other politicians may say similar things.

What are the problems with this way of thinking?

Two in my view: It ignores or at least underestimates the power of rule of law, and it jumps to conclusions prematurely. I will discuss each below in turn.

Keeping Rule of Law in Mind

There are “China haters” who would criticize anything and everything China does and would push the US away from doing anything remotely similar to what China is doing or has done. But they forget — ironically for lawmakers — that the key difference between China and the US is rule of law: The latter has it, but the former has not.

Under the current leadership of Xi Jinping, China clearly shows more interests in “rule of party” than rule of law. It would be a shameful waste if the US follows a strategy of eschewing anything China does, because the US has long existing and detailed laws to protect citizens’ privacy, while China can only resort to its top leaders’ goodwill or personal preferences.

To be sure, China has come from a long way behind and has made long strides of progresses. There is no better way to summarize the situation than simply saying that time has changed. Even the top leaders can no longer do what their processors could do. If China shifts from Xi Jinping to “Wang Jinping” or “Li Jinping,” whoever takes the helms today is unlikely to go back to Mao’s era completely.

As a good example, just when seemingly everyone in the US or EU is accusing China as a surveillance state, even with a model to link surveillance cameras with internal citizen control to turn everyone into his own policeman. Few has bothered to mention the fact that “(r)oughly 770 million surveillance cameras are in use today, and that number is expected to jump to one billion by 2021, according to a market forecast reported by the Wall Street Journal last year.

China has also moved toward guarding citizens’ privacy. According to the BIS (Bank of International Settlement) 2021 report, which cites different approaches taken by countries to protect citizens’ privacy, China’s version of CBDC, called e-CNY, “is to shield the identity of the user by designating the user’s public key, which is issued by the mobile phone operator, as the digital ID. The central bank would not have access to the underlying personal details.”

Yet China still has a long way to go, and the strong legal guardrail preventing power abuse, like the system we see in the US, is simply not there. Missing that, Chinese citizens can still only count on the goodwill of top leaders and little else. This is likely to be the key and long lasting advantage the US has over China.

Sometimes I get angry after repeatedly seeing public events taking (the usual) bad turns in China, where governments have the knee-jerk reactions case after case: blocking the news from spreading instead of addressing the root of the problems. Take a look at this latest example of a trafficked woman who was chained to a small shed after producing eight children. What the ABC News report did not mention is that local governments, while promising to conduct a thorough investigation and “detained six people and fired eight lower-level Communist Party officials,” are also investigating who gave the pictures to the media that caused a big fuss on the domestic Internet. These are exactly the kind of developments that kills my confidence in China’s system — the same confidence that Xi Jinping told the world to have with China.  

“Have faith in your own institutions. Know your competitors but first, know yourself better.” These are the words I want to say to some Americans.

Tactic vs. Strategic Institutions

It is important to remember that CBDC is not an institution standing by itself, separating from everything else. CBDC is not falling from the sky and randomly landing itself anywhere in the world, either. It is not CBDC that creates authoritarianism, just like it is not Bitcoin that will turn a country into democracy. CBDC and Bitcoin are what I call “tactical institutions.” It is the bigger, higher level — the “strategic institution” of rule of law — or lack thereof, that controls the nature of CBDC.

The BIS 2021 report, my favorite document on the CBDC topic, says it well: “The same technology that can encourage a virtuous circle of greater access, lower costs and better services might equally induce a vicious circle of data silos, market power and anti-competitive practices.” Furthermore, “whether a jurisdiction chooses to introduce CBDCs, FPS or other systems will depend on the efficiency of their legacy payment systems, economic development, legal frameworks and user preferences, as well as their aims.”

Rule of Law Brings Surprises

One way to understand and to remember what rule of law is about is to think of it as capable of bringing “surprises.” Without rule of law, those who are stronger and more resourceful would “logically” dominate those weaker and less resourceful. Without rule of law, those who have free access to precious information would “naturally” use it anyway they see fit with little consequence. Without rule of law, those at a higher hierarchical position would “normally” smash or abuse those below anyway pleases them and expect little repercussion.

But rule of law changes all that, and there is very little left to be taken for granted with rule of law. Think you can ­dominate the less powerful others? Think again! Think you can use all the information you have access to? Sorry but think again! Think you can wield all your positional power on your subordinates, once again it would be smarter to think again!

Why are those “surprises” good for the society? Because (1) they send a signal out that justice is possible; (2) they bring at least some power to the presumably powerless; (3) they turn the world into a more level playing field than other models of social governance where rule of law is missing or weakening; (4) they prevent “winner takes all” from happening, at least from happening all the time; and (5) they redefine strength and weakness not by a single type of resource but multiple types.

Simply put, the biggest advantage of rule of law is to organize and mobilize social resources, public or private, by transparent, carefully designed and universally applied rules. Xi Jinping of China does not believe it and is trying to revive the legacy “rule of men” system. He is wasting time — his and China’s. The best test of rule of law is how many surprises like those listed above an average citizen will encounter on an average day. Until China someday proves itself capable of producing more surprises, China is still a weak country no matter how big its GDP figures are.

Don’t get me wrong: Rule of law will not be completely watertight or completely bulletproof but acts like human immune system: the most efficient, adaptive and holistic first line of defense.

In the case of CBDC, rule of law changes the question to be asked: It is not whether central banks have direct access to citizens’ private information or not, but what they can do about it and what consequence they must face in case of abuse, that separates authoritarianism and democracy.

Of course, we can design the CBDC model such that central banks do not always or do not automatically have direct access to citizens’ transactions data. I will come to that point later.

Is Nakamoto Too Radical?

I know there are many enthusiasts out there who would accept nothing but Satoshi Nakamoto and his Bitcoin. With all due respect for the pioneer, Nakamoto has shown a tendency to forget or to underestimate the power of rule of law. He designed Bitcoin in a way like it was in the wild and lawless west. As a result, Nakamoto and his Bitcoin bring truly radical changes.

A good framework of evaluation is to consider the three dimensions of an information system: architecture (concentrated or distributed), access (permissionless or permissioned) and control (centralized or decentralized) as discussed in this insightful essay.

Nakamoto goes all the way to change all three dimensions at the same time by making Bitcoin a distributed ledger (i.e., financial bookkeeping records distributed over numerous public nodes with redundant copies), with completely open (i.e., “permissionless”) access and entirely decentralized control. His design came at the time when we had an entirely concentrated, permissioned and centralized monetary system. Bitcoin was consciously made as the anti-thesis of the status quo.

When someone tries to do too much at a single shot, the solution is inevitably radical rather than balanced. This does not mean the proposal will be a total failure. Consider Warren Buffett who used to call Bitcoin “rat poison” years ago, but just invested $1 billion to a cryptocurrency friendly bank, Nubank based in Brazil. It is safe to say that Bitcoin is here to stay.

However, radical solutions tend to have an excessive cost. As the BIS (Bank for International Settlement) 2021 report points out, “it is clear that cryptocurrencies are speculative assets rather than money, and in many cases are used to facilitate money laundering, ransomware attacks and other financial crimes. Bitcoin in particular has few redeeming public interest attributes when also considering its wasteful energy footprint.

Even Bitcoin fans or early adapters have voted by feet. In terms of picking the best crypto exchanges the centralized exchanges (Coinbase, Binance, Kraken & Gemini) are far more popular than decentralized ones as discussed in this Investopedia article. The latter also do not necessarily do better than their centralized counterparts in safety. According to this Wikipedia article, “(i)n July 2018, decentralized exchange Bancor was reportedly hacked and suffered a loss of $13.5M in assets before freezing funds.”

By the way, I have little doubt that Satoshi Nakamoto is the person’s real Japanese name because his words and deeds match the behavioral pattern under the influence of Confucianism.

While being modest and maintaining a low key in spite of great success is a virtue, I wish Nakamoto had some exposure to psychology to help him understand imposing constraints in access, control and architecture is itself a valuable incentive, while leaving everything open can be a big turnoff because it can significantly weaken the sense of individual responsibility.

China has a famous proverbial story that says a Buddhist temple was deeply hidden in the mountain and people had to go downhill to get drinking water. First there was just one monk in the temple, who always carried two buckets of water on his shoulder and climbed uphill. Life was hard but manageable. Later one more monk joined the temple, and the two decided they both should share the responsibility of getting one bucket of water uphill as nobody wanted to be the one carrying two buckets. Soon another monk came and since none of them wanted to be the “water carrier,” the three all died of thirst.

So the famous saying goes: One monk = 2 buckets of water, two monks = 1 bucket of water and three monks = 0 bucket of water (一个和尚挑水喝,两个和尚抬水喝,三个和尚没水喝).

In the Nakamoto’s case, according to this article published in August 2021, there were 12,130 public nodes running on the Bitcoin network. Such a global “temple of Nakamoto” is much larger than three “monks.”

But my intention is never to mock all free and open entities as the “temple of three monks.” Instead, I strongly believe temples of one, two or three monks should all be allowed to exist, at least to try out. Diversity makes life beautiful, while the same model of life never fits everyone.  

How Rule of Law Helps Protect Privacy

I have two counterarguments to weaken the equation of CBDC = Authoritarianism. First of all, not everything is to be changed by CBDC. At the end of day, customers own their transaction records and have the right to keep them private. Shifting from commercial banks to central bank (if the US decides on a “retail CBDC” model, see later for details) will not change that. The same laws and regulations should apply tomorrow as they do today. Following my thesis of “rule of law = surprises,” laws offer protection to the weaker, less resourceful agents, entities or parties. Just because someone has access to free information does not mean they are free to use it anyway they want.

Secondly, while CBDC may allow central banks easier access to transaction records than before, pending on which business CBDC model we choose to follow, one may argue that the risk exposure will be lower rather than higher today. With about 85,000 branch offices of commercial banks in the country according to this article in Harvard Business Review (HBR), all allowed to access or to hold customers’ transaction records, hacker attacks and information leaks are bound to happen. The same HBR article says that the “cost of fraud to U.S. financial services companies is estimated at 1.5% of revenues, or around $15 billion annually.” By handing over the records to the central bank (again pending on the retail CBDC model, which may not be the best) that is better equipped with security resources than commercial banks do, we expect fewer attacks, although each attack may be more devastating if it does happen, as the loss will be higher.

The moral of the story is that we hardly ever see decisions completely risk free. Far more likely we will face trade-offs that force us to weigh benefits and costs, to compare solutions and to arrive at the conditionally best choice.

Enough for philosophical talks and let us see which business model of CBDC will allow us to avoid or mitigate some costs and seek more benefits from transitions. Before doing that, however, we have to clear one more mental hurdle first.

A Little Patience Helps Everyone

The second problem with the “CBDC = Authoritarianism” equation is lack of patience to jump to conclusions too quickly, which reduces the possibility of keeping an open mind. This may not seem a big deal but lacking patience can be fatal for developing good, sensible and smooth agenda of changes.

The last time I checked, with China moving the fastest, not a single CBDC project on the face of the earth has been set in stone. We are seeing white papers, proof of concept and experimentations. There are just too many variables and too little certainty at this moment.

To begin, it is not even sure that all CBDC models will have the central bank getting all the retail transaction information. To be sure, some fintech experts, like Ajay S. Mookerjee in an HBR essay, seem to favor retail CBDC when he pictures “a scenario in which every citizen has, in essence, a checking account with the Central Bank” that makes “the central bank effectively becoming the sole intermediary for financial transactions” and “becomes the lender of first rather than last resort,” therefore eliminating all “bank runs” and the need for FDIC insurance as “the depositor carries no risk.”

The Three CBDC Business Models

I am not sure whether such a scenario will arrive anytime soon — if ever — with any degree of certainty. You do not have to listen to me but do listen to what banking experts have to say. In the 2021 BIS (Bank of International Settlement) report cited earlier, the authors summarized three CBDC models (in Graph III.7), although less informative and less insightful discussions can be found elsewhere by Ernst Young and McKinsey.

First we have “direct CBDC” or retail CBDC, in which the central bank is dealing with every individual customer, be it business or household, covering all operational tasks with user-facing activities like account opening, maintenance and enforcement of money laundering.

This is the least likely model that the Fed will follow. I know this because on Jan. 20, 2022, seven days before Strobel publishedheropinion in Newsweek, the Federal Reserve Board (FRB) released a discussion paper on the pros and cons of creating a central bank digital currency (CBDC) for the United States. In the paper, which invites public comment through May 20, 2022, the FRB already makes it clear that the US CBDC “must be intermediated (the private sector, not the Fed, would offer accounts or digital wallets to facilitate the management of CBDC holdings and payments).” The reason: Such a model would ignore or bypass all the intermediaries of commercial banks and other fintech players, who are better equipped to deal with retail customers than the central bank does.

Direct CBDC model also means the central banks will act like Strobel has claimed as a “money printer” (i.e., regulating monetary policy) and “personal banker” at the same time, which is not a smart idea — not for ideological reasons but for efficiency considerations. But if one must look at the issue from a pure ideological lens, something Strobel is clearly doing, I would say direct CBDC model smells more like authoritarianism than the wholesale model does, as the former inevitably leads to a much deeper penetration of citizens’ financial lives than the latter does.

The second model is what BIS calls “hybrid” CBDC architecture, in which the private sector “onboards all clients, is responsible for enforcing AML/CFT (i.e., anti-money laundering and counter-terrorist financing)regulations and ongoing due diligence and conducts all retail payments in real time. However, the central bank also records retail balances.” According to BIS, “The e-CNY, the CBDC issued by the People’s Bank of China and currently in a trial phase, exemplifies such a hybrid design.” As I quoted above, it looks like the FRB will also be on board, as well as the European Central Bank (ECB).

With such a model, existing financial institutions like banks and other financial or fintech entities will be handling customers’ digital accounts. Although CBDC is the sole liability of central bank — just like hard cash is — operationally the private sector is not “off the hook” from the CBDC liability. In case when hackers attack, separating customers into different financial institutions makes the risk containable at local level. One may even say that this model is resonant with the decentralized and defused blockchain technology, despite the debate on whether permissioned (or private) blockchains, with which CBDC fits better than with public or permissionless blockchains, can be counted as genuine blockchain (I believe they should, see more later).

The last model discussed by BIS is the “intermediated” CBDC, which has been more commonly referred to as the “wholesale CBDC.” As the name implies, wholesale CBDC limits interactions of central bank to financial institutions, where central banks will run a wholesale ledger, although “PSPs (Payment Service Providers) would need to be closely supervised to ensure at all times that the wholesale holdings they communicate to the central bank indeed add up to the sum of all retail accounts.

A recent (undated) report by Ernest Young (EY) entitled “Crypto Assets the Global Regulation Perspective” (in downloadable PDF) also points out that the wholesale (i.e., with intermediation) model leverages existing (private) financial institutions to make CBDC like a central bank reserve account, “leaving a considerable role for existing market participants, such as banks and payments providers, avoiding the risk of disintermediation, and alleviating central banks from operational tasks such as customer due diligence (CDD) procedures.”

BIS is in favor of the hybrid model and urges CBDC to avoid a large footprint in retail and consumer facing financial activities, and instead to allow financial intermediaries to do what they do best: “CBDCs are best designed as part of a two-tier system, where the central bank and the private sector each play their respective role. A logical step in their design is to delegate the majority of operational tasks and consumer facing activities to commercial banks and non-bank PSPs that provide retail services on a competitive level playing field.”

This is the conclusion I like. Of the three models, direct (aka, retail) CBDC marks the largest deviation from the current central bank functionalities, while the wholesale model is likely to produce the least amount of changes from the current role of central banks. The hybrid model sits in between the two.

Privacy Has Not Been Forgotten

The BIS 2021 report has a separate section on how to identify and safeguard privacy of customers. It compares two models of the “token-based” versus “account-based.” BIS concludes that “a token-based CBDC which comes with full anonymity could facilitate illegal activity and is therefore unlikely to serve the public interest.” Instead, “Identification at some level is hence central in the design of CBDCs. This calls for a CBDC that is account-based and ultimately tied to a digital identity, but with safeguards on data privacy as additional features.”

It is not particularly hard to sell the idea of account based model, given the current system all demand for establishing accounts. The key challenge is how to balance digital money safety and privacy. The former is essentially about public safety like cyberattacks, money laundering and financial theft, while the latter about individual safety like identity theft, data abuse or even personal safety. “Consequently, it is most useful to implement anonymity with respect to specific parties, such as PSPs, businesses or public agencies. CBDC designs can allow for privacy by separating payment services from control over the resulting data.” “CBDCs could give users control over their payments data, which they need only share with PSPs or third parties as they decide.

In other words, just because CBDC is issued by the central bank does not mean the latter has automatic access to transactions information involving CBDC. This is not much different from hard cash, which is also issued by central bank and yet the latter has only limited knowledge of how every dollar is paid by whom to whom, unless it involves a hefty sum of cash.

Every party, other than the owner of the data, including government agencies, should only have access to transaction information at a “need to know” basis, nobody possesses automatic and sweeping rights. That way, the users maintain their data right and ownership, everyone else would take access as a privilege rather than as a right.

My Grand View of CBDC

I am not as “left leaning” as Satoshi Nakamoto is and I prefer not to discuss decisions or choices based on value judgements alone. I also do not see the need of treating governments as inevitably public enemies. They are just human created institutions with strengths and weaknesses like all of us do.

Although I do not judge others by the values they hold, I do hold my own value preference or value proposal. I care most about two things: Institutional inclusiveness and transitional efficiency. I call for the most preferred — also the least costly — scenario to emerge at the end of the transition period, in which central banks and decentralized cryptocurrencies will stay together rather than to kill or defeat each other. Given that, as pointed out by BIS, CBDC offers the unique advantages of “settlement finality, liquidity and integrity” for the digital economy, I entitled this post “CBDC by All Means.”

When a new innovation emerges from the horizon, we have always seen fans so enthusiastic that they predict the new innovation will wipe out or obsolete the old ones. History frequently proved them wrong because it takes time and trial-and-error for society to become aware, enticed, learn and eventually accept the new and drop down the old ones. This is a tall order and sometimes we may have to rely on the nature to get the job done. For example, we may have to wait until the entire old generation passed away to completely obsolete the land line phones.

History has also shown repeatedly that institutional inclusiveness pays. Humans are better off by having both centralized and decentralized controls, both open and limited accesses, both concentrated and distributed power /information structure.

These three dimensions — control, access & architecture — are discussed by this academic article, to which I want to add two more: Humans need both trusted and trust-free exchanges and we also need both disintermediated and intermediated transactions. I know some Bitcoin supporters strongly prefer disintermediation of anything, but the truth is that we often end up replacing one intermediary by another. Coinbase is a good example. Cryptocurrency traders do get rid of the traditional banks, but they pick up Coinbase or other (centralized) exchanges.

Will Central Bank Have Total Control of All Transactions?

To see why the US CBDC will not “give the government total control and oversight over every person’s holdings and transactions” like Strobel claims, let us first see what the Fed had said. On Jan. 20, 2022, seven days before Strobel publishedheropinion in Newsweek, the Federal Reserve Board (FRB) released a discussion paper on the pros and cons of creating a central bank digital currency (CBDC) for the United States. In the paper, which invites public comment through May 20, 2022, the Fed specifically notes that if a U.S. CBDC is created, it should “(c)omplement, rather than replace, current forms of money and methods for providing financial services.”

In other words, it is not in Fed’s plan to wipe out traditional forms of fiat money and to replace it with CBDC. This means even if every CBDC dollar is used for the evil “authoritarian” purposes, the Fed cannot gain “total control and oversight over every person’s holdings and transactions” like Strobel said, because traditional forms of fiat money will continue to exist — unless one regards all government issued money as authoritarian tokens.

If the goal is to gain the best control of all transactions, the Fed is better off replacing current forms of money by CBDC. This is because transactions using hard cash are still harder to be tracked than digital money. Drug dealers and money launderers often transact by paying cash, as recently reported by a credible study of SWIFT (Society for Worldwide Interbank Financial Telecommunication), rather than paying crypto.

The fact that the Fed is not pushing for complete replacement of cash by CBDC means it has something else in mind. Perhaps reducing the shock of radical transition or waiting for the blockchain technology to become more mature? It is safe to say there are multiple considerations in which controlling for transactions is just one of them.

What If All Fiat Money Is Gone?

But let’s stop guessing what is on Fed’s mind and simply assume Fed wants to replace all traditional forms of fiat money in the future. Furthermore, let’s also assume all governments want the same thing: controlling and overseeing everyone’s transactions. Now, with these assumptions will CBDC help the Fed achieve that goal?

The answer has to be “No!” In order to control all transactions, it is insufficient to make CBDC the only form of fiat money. We already know the reason: Even if the Fed makes CBDC a legal tender (i.e., the money that is legally established as satisfactory payment), which is certainly in the plan if the Fed decides to go with CBDC, CBDC will not be the only digital currency available in the market to cover all transactions. Other cryptocurrencies are already there. The only way for CBDC to have full control is to wipe out, or to drive out of circulation, all cryptocurrencies not issued by central banks. This would bring us back to the old days when Fed issued fiat money is the only currency available for all transactions in the market.

CBDC & Monopoly Power of Central Banks

How likely is it for the Fed to eliminate all cryptocurrencies so that its CBDC will be only legal tender and used exclusively for all transactions by all people? It is extremely unlikely. The reason is not because of the love affair between central banks and cryptocurrencies. If you know the history of Bitcoin, you should know that Satoshi Nakamoto created Bitcoin not to pave the way for CBDC to come later but exactly the opposite: to win a major battle in the arms race with government. Nakamoto was not shy in saying it out loudly why he wanted a decentralized currency: “Governments are good at cutting off the heads of a centrally controlled networks like Napster, but pure P2P networks like Gnutella and Tor seem to be holding their own.”

We now know the story after Nakamoto said that: Blockchains and cryptocurrencies have won a battle with the government — more generally with the central control of currencies. The fact that the Fed is talking about CBDC is a sure sign of that victory. It is like the old saying: If you can’t beat them, join them, which is what the Fed said it may do next.

Given this scenario, it is clear that CBDC will have to learn to co-exist with other crypto that emerged before it. This Investopedia article even asks about the possibility for cryptocurrencies to dismantle the central bank. Although that is unlikely, nor beneficial, to happen, it is clear that the crypto has dismantled the monopoly power of the central banks (see more on this later), not the bank itself. To break up or to end a monopoly all it takes is for a single unit of non-Fed issued cryptocurrency, be it Bitcoin, Litecoin, Ethereum or Dogecoin, to legally exists in the market. This is exactly what we are seeing today. In California, it is even proposed to make the cryptocurrency a legal tender, meaning it will be — if passed as law — perfectly legal to pay workers, consumers or citizens with cryptocurrency.

To governments’ ears the existence of even one unit of cryptocurrency is like a loud crack of thunder, which explains why so many people are talking about how monetary policies would be impacted in the future.

Debate on Permissioned Blockchain

The only weakness of the 2021 BIS report is that it barely touched on the technical issues involved in blockchain. There is an ongoing debate on whether permissioned (i.e., private) blockchains should be counted as a genuine blockchains. This is directly relevant to CBDC, which is more likely to sit in a private blockchain. A private blockchain is still a “distributed secure database,” which is the nature of all blockchains. If both central bank and commercial banks following the hybrid, two-tier architecture maintain databases of their own on CBDC related transactions, they would form a distributed ledger.

Even limited redundancy, meaning a few entities keeping repeated and redundant ledgers of the same transactions, is better than a single centralized ledger. The Fed could form an alliance with centralized cryptocurrency exchanges (the most successful ones like Coinbase, Binance, Kraken, and Gemini), that would boost up security. Say the Fed asks Coinbase to accept and to deposit CBDC for citizens, and both Fed and Coinbase keep separate ledgers for these customers, that would be a good idea, given these exchanges’ more experience with digital money than ordinary banks. 

Permissioned blockchain like this will not be open to everyone in the society but can still implement the key security features commonly seen in a blockchain, like the hash function (more strictly cryptocurrency hash function), Merkle tree, digital signatures (public and private keys), Proof of Work (PoW) and the longest chain protocol. Ultimately it is up to the alliance to try and to decide how far into the existing blockchain technology is the best for them.

A more interesting discussion is in this lecture note from Stanford University, where the instructor talks about how we can have the best of two worlds: Nakamoto + BFT (Byzantine Fault Tolerance). The latter is like CBDC to allow a permissioned system of static participation, unlike Bitcoin as a permissionless system of dynamic participation. Again, this means institutional inclusiveness wins over exclusiveness.

The US History of Money

I thought I had said all the things I wanted to say but thanks to this Investopedia article and also this lecture note, I learned an important fact that money is not always the way we know it today. Before the Federal Reserve, the US central bank, came into the scene, “(m)oney issued by non-bank entities like merchants and municipal corporations proliferated throughout the U.S. monetary system. The exchange rates for each of these currencies varied, and many were frauds, not backed by enough gold reserves to justify their valuations. Bank runs and panics periodically convulsed through the U.S. economy.”

The US emerged successfully from those chaotic — but little known or long forgotten — days and came up with a central bank system. “Immediately after the Civil War, the National Currency Act of 1863 and the National Bank Act of 1864 helped set the grounding for a centralized and federal system of money.A uniform national banknote that was redeemable at face value in commercial centers across the country was issued. Further to this, the Federal Reserve’s creation in 1913 brought monetary and financial stability to the economy.”

This story reminds me of the words from one of the most famous novels in China: Stories of the Three Kingdoms (三国演义). The author summarized Chinese history with a tendance to see people uniting after a long period of fighting, and fighting after a long period of uniting (天下大势,分久必合,合久必分). Translating this line of thinking to the history of US currency, we may say the money started from being decentralized to centralized and now is poised to go back to decentralization, thanks to the co-existence of crypto, CBDC and blockchains.

Categories
Financial talks at dinner table

Introducing the Family Members in the Financial Talks at the Dinner Table

Cleo (6 year old, 1st grader) & Jason (10 year old, 5th grader), the youngest daughter and son in the Kingston family

Emily (13 year old, 8th grader), the third daughter in the family

Kimberly (18 year old, 12th grader), second daughter

Lily (20 year old, college student), first daughter

Joy Kingston (48 year old), Mom, a managerial consultant

Greg Kingston (50 year old), Dad, a college professor in Finance

All images are downloaded from the Creative Commons collection and inserted into pages of Microsoft Office Publisher.

Everyone in this fictional family “contributes” equally to the conversations.